Defining Trade Secret
The UTSA, now in force in
45 U.S. states, defines trade secret as follows:
A trade secret is any
information, including a formula, pattern, compilation, device, method,
technique, or process, that: (i) derives independent economic value, actual or
potential, from not being generally known to, and not being readily
ascertainable by proper means by, other persons who can obtain economic value
from its disclosure or use, and (ii) is the subject of efforts that are
reasonable under the circumstances to maintain its secrecy.
The most widely used
definition, from 1929, of trade secret is found in the
Restatement of Torts.3 It reads:
A trade secret may
consist of any formula, pattern, device or compilation of information which is
used in one’s business, and which gives him [or her] an opportunity to obtain
an advantage over competitors who do not know or use it. It may be a formula for
a chemical compound, a process of manufacturing, treating or preserving
materials, a pattern for a machine or other device, or a list of customers.4
In applying this 1929
definition to determine whether trade secrets exist, courts have relied on the
following criteria:
- extent to which the information is
known outside of the business
- extent to which it is known by
employees and others involved in the business
- measures taken to guard the secrecy of
the information
- value of the information to the
business and to competitors
- amount of effort or money expended in
developing the information
- ease or difficulty with which the
information could be properly acquired or duplicated by others
The most recent and, in
this author’s view, the broadest and best definition of trade secret is
set forth in Restatement (Third) of Unfair Competition:5
A trade secret is any
information that can be used in the operation of a business or other enterprise
and that is sufficiently valuable and secret to afford an actual or potential
economic advantage over others.
This definition most
likely will eventually replace the earlier definitions. As of 1996, the
Economic Espionage Act (EEA), a federal criminal trade-secret statute, includes
the following definition:
(A) The term trade secret
means all forms and types of financial, business, scientific, technical,
economic, or engineering information, including patterns, plans, compilations,
program devices, formulas, designs, prototypes, methods, techniques, processes,
procedures, programs, or codes, whether tangible or intangible, and whether or
how stored, compiled, or memorialized physically, electronically, graphically,
photographically, or in writing if —
(B) the owner thereof has
taken reasonable measures to keep such information secret; and the information
derives independent economic value, actual or potential, from not being
generally known to, and not being readily ascertainable through proper means
by, the public.
3. What is and what is
not a Trade Secret
The definitions included
above provide a fairly clear picture of what constitutes a trade secret. At the
most basic level, a trade secret is simply information and knowledge. More
specifically, it is any proprietary technical or business information, often
embodied in inventions, know-how, and show-how. The definitions roughly agree
on three requirements that must be met for enforceable trade secrets to exist.
The proprietary information must be:
- secret, in the sense that it is not
generally known in the trade
- valuable to competitors that do not
possess it
- the subject of reasonable efforts to
safeguard and maintain it in secrecy
There are critical
limitations on trade secrets and pitfalls in trade-secret enforcement and
litigation. The requirement to maintain secrecy is a frequent pitfall.
Moreover, any information that is readily ascertainable, or is derived from the
personal skills of employees, cannot be considered an enforceable trade secret.
Trade secret protection
applies not just to manufacturing processes, early stage inventions, and
subpatentable innovations, as is sometimes believed. Patentable inventions can
be considered trade secrets; this was made clear in the Supreme Court decision
in Kewanee Oil v. Bicron, which recognized trade secrets as
perfectly viable alternatives to patents.6 In
holding that state trade-secret law is not preempted by the federal patent law,
the court tellingly held:
Certainly the patent
policy of encouraging invention is not disturbed by the existence of another
form of incentive to invention. In this respect, the two systems are not and
never would be in conflict.… Trade secret law and patent law have coexisted in
this country for over one hundred years. Each has its particular role to play,
and the operation of one does not take away from the need for the other.… We
conclude that the extension of trade-secret protection (even) to clearly
patentable inventions does not conflict with the patent policy of disclosure.
Since the essence of the
patent system is the public disclosure of inventions, it is sometimes suggested
that keeping inventions secret is wrong. This is a serious misconception. The
decision in Dunlop Holdings v. Ram Golf made clear that the
public benefits from trade secrets. Trade secrets generally do not suppress
economic activity, because employees, suppliers, licensees, and others are
given access to the necessary information.7 Additionally,
given the high incidence of employee mobility and inadvertent or deliberate
leakage, many trade secrets dissipate within a few years. Possible reverse
engineering and analysis of products are additional ways that trade secrets may
dissipate or become compromised. In other words, trade secrets are secret only
in a limited legal sense.
Contrary to conventional
wisdom, trade-secret protection can be used in conjunction with patents to
protect the tremendous volume of associated know-how that exists for any
patentable invention but that cannot be disclosed in a patent specification.
It is useful, also, to
specify the use of the terms know-how and trade secret.
While the key requirement of a trade secret is secrecy, know-how does not
necessarily require or imply secrecy, as can be seen from the following
definitions:
- the knowledge and skill required to do
something correctly.8
- information that enables one to
accomplish a particular task or to operate a particular device or process.9
- knowledge and experience of a
technical, commercial, administrative, financial or other nature, which is
practically applicable in the operation of an enterprise or the practice
of a profession.10
Know-how is not
protectable as an IP right. Know-how acquires trade-secret status only if it is
secret and has economic value and if measures are in place to secure its
secrecy. Know-how is intellectual property, however, and is protected if it qualifies
as a trade secret. Since we do not speak of “invention and patent licenses,” it
is likewise inappropriate to refer to “know-how and trade-secret licenses.”
4. History of Trade
Secrets
Trade secret law is the
oldest form of IP protection. In ancient Rome, trade secret laws established
legal consequences for a person who induced another’s employee (or slave) to
divulge secrets relating to the master’s commercial affairs. Trade secrecy was
practiced extensively in Medieval European guilds. Modern trade-secret law,
however, evolved in the early 19th century, in England, in response to the
growing accumulation of technology and know-how and the increased mobility of
employees. In 1868, a Massachusetts court held, inPeabody v. Norfolk,
that a secret manufacturing process was considered property, and was
protectable against misappropriation, and that a secrecy obligation for an
employee outlasted the term of employment. The decision also held that a trade
secret can be disclosed confidentially to others who need to practice it, and
that a recipient can be enjoined from using a misappropriated trade secret. Peabody
v. Norfolk clearly anticipated the main features of our present
trade-secret system, and by the end of the 19th century the principal aspects
of contemporary law were well established.11
5. Importance of Trade
Secrets
Trade secrets are the
crown jewels of corporations. Indeed, trade secrets are now even more relevant
than they were a few decades ago as a tool for protecting innovation, and the
stakes involved in their protection are getting higher. Injunctions are now a
greater threat in trade-secret misappropriation cases than only a decade ago,
and damage awards have been in the hundreds of millions of U.S. dollars in
recent years. In a recent trial in Orlando, Florida, two businessmen were
seeking US$1.4 billion in damages from the Walt Disney Company, accusing them
of stealing trade secrets for use in a Walt Disney World sports complex. The
jury awarded the businessmen US$240 million.12 In
another recent case, Cargill, Inc. was found to have misappropriated
genetic-corn-seed trade secrets belonging to then Pioneer Hi-Bred
International, Inc., and was forced to pay US$300 million. In another instance,
Lexar won US$465.4 million in damages from Toshiba for misappropriation of
controller technology that enabled a memory chip to communicate with its host
device.13
Mark Halligan recently
proclaimed, “Trade secrets are the IP of the new millennium and can no
longer be treated as a stepchild.” James Pooley concurred, “Forget
patents, trademarks and copyrights… trade secrets could be your company’s most
important and valuable assets.”14 Henry
Perritt15 said trade secrets are “the
oldest form of IP protection,” and that, “patent law was developed as a
way of protecting trade secrets without requiring them to be kept secret and
thereby discouraging wider use of useful information.” This interpretation
makes patents a supplement to trade secrets, rather than the other way around.
In fact, according to a
2003 survey on strategic IP management sponsored by the Intellectual Property
Owners Association (IPO), patents are rarely viewed as an IP panacea, but
rather as a supplement to other forms of IP protection.16 Patents
have limits, such as early publication, invent-around feasibility, and strict
patentability requirements. Survey respondents did rate proprietary technology
highly as a key source of competitive advantage, and a large majority of
respondents (88%) cited skills and knowledge as the most important intellectual
assets. Trade secrets are therefore directly implicated in the protection of
proprietary skills and knowledge.
Moreover, patents are
only the tips of icebergs in an ocean of trade secrets. Over 90% of all new
technology is covered by trade secrets. And over 80% of all license and
technology transfer agreements cover proprietary know-how (trade secrets) or
are hybrid agreements covering both patents and trade secrets. Bob Sherwood, an
international IP consultant, calls trade secrets the “workhorse[s] of
technology transfer.”
Finally, and very
importantly, trade-secret protection operates without delay and without undue
cost, while patents are territorial, expensive to obtain, and can be acquired
only in certain countries.
6. Trade Secret
Characteristics
From the above
trade-secret definitions, we can understand the following salient
characteristics of trade secrets and how they differ substantially from other
types of IP rights.
For trade secrets, there
is no subject matter or term limitation, registration or tangibility
requirement. Furthermore, there is no strict novelty requirement, and
trade-secret protection obtains as long as the subject matter is not generally
known or available.
What does matter
is secrecy—that the information is not known by outsiders. And maintaining
secrecy requires reasonable affirmative measures to safeguard it. Such measures
might include:
- stipulating in writing a trade-secret
policy
- informing employees of the
trade-secret policy
- having employees sign employment
agreements with confidentiality obligations
- restricting access to trade-secrets
(on a need-to-know basis)
- restricting public accessibility and
escorting visitors
- locking gates and cabinets to sites
that house trade secrets
- labeling trade-secret documents as
proprietary and confidential
- screening the speeches and
publications of employees
- using secrecy contracts in dealing
with third parties
- conducting exit interviews with departing
employees
It is important to
consider that while sufficient economic value or competitive advantage is
significant, the proper touchstone for a trade secret is not actual use but
only value to the owner. This means that negative R&D results
can give a competitive advantage (just as positive results can), in that the
owner of the information has a greater knowledge of what are, and what
are not, feasible and/or viable options for further commercialization. If
competitors become privy to what is not feasible, by sidestepping known blind
alleys, their R&D activities can accelerate, and any strategic or
competitive advantage originally held by the owner will diminish.
Finally, the
misappropriation of trade secrets is actionable if the secrets were acquired improperly,
if a trade secret that was acquired improperly is either used or disclosed, or
if an individual violates a duty to maintain confidentiality. A trade secret is
acquired by improper means if it was obtained through theft,
bribery, misrepresentation, breach or inducement of a breach of a duty to
maintain secrecy, or through espionage, including electronic espionage.
Remedies for misappropriation of trade secrets include actual and punitive
damages, profits, reasonable royalties, and injunctions. The proper
means of acquiring a trade secret (which do not support a claim for
misappropriation) include independent discovery, reverse engineering, chemical
analysis, or discovery from observing what has been allowed to enter the public
domain.
7. Integration of IP
Rights
Literature and
presentations on IP strategies, IP valuation, and other IP topics almost always
address patents and patent portfolios. This focus on patents, however,
overlooks the fact that legal protection of innovations of any kind, especially
in high-tech fields, requires the use of more than one IP category. This
overlap assures dual or multiple protections.
Jay Dratler, in his Intellectual
Property Law: Commercial, Creative, and Industrial Property, was the first
to “tie all the fields of IP together.” According to Dratler, IP rights,
formerly fragmented by specialties, are now a “seamless web” due to
progress in technology and commerce.17 Six
years later in 1997, the authors of Intellectual Property in the New
Technological Age also stressed the need to “avoid the fragmented
coverage… by approaching IP as a unified whole” and by concentrating on the
“interaction between different types of IP rights.”18 Today,
we have a unified theory of IP management, a single field of law with subsets,
and a significant overlap between IP fields. Several IP rights are available
for the same IP or for different aspects of the same IP. Not taking advantage
of the overlap misses opportunities, and, according to Dratler, amounts to a
kind of “malpractice.”
Especially for high-tech
products, trademarks and copyrights can supplement patents, trade secrets, and
mask works (“blueprints” used in the R&D and production of semiconductor
chips). One IP category, often patents, may be the “center of gravity” in
certain instances. Other IP rights categories are then supplemental but equally
valuable. The supplemental forms of IP may function to:
- cover additional subject matter
- strengthen exclusivity
- invoke additional remedies in
litigation
- provide a backup if a primary IP right
becomes invalid, thus providing synergy and optimal legal protection
Dratler provides the
following examples:
a) Multiple protection
for a data processing system can involve:
- patented hardware and software
- patented computer architecture on
circuit designs
- trade-secret production processes
- copyrighted microcode
- copyrighted operating system
- copyrighted instruction manual
- semiconductor chips protected as mask
works
- consoles or keyboards protected by
design patents, or as trade dress under trademark principles
- trademark registration
b) Multiple protection
for a diagnostic kit involving monoclonal antibodies:
- product patent on the test kit
- process patent on the preparation of
the antibodies
- trade secrecy for production know-how
- copyright for test kit’s instructions
- trademark
Even these examples are
somewhat limited, because trade secrets can protect not only know-how and
processes, but also large amounts of collateral data, information, and other
know-how that are not found in patent specifications.
Other valuable examples:
c) Multiple protection of
aesthetic designs:
- patent
- copyright for separable features
- trademark for nonfunctional features
- trade dress for overall appearance
- utility patent for functional features
- trade secrets for collateral and
collateral know-how and data
d) Multiple protection
for plants and plant parts:
To encapsulate the IP
integration concept, numerous practitioners recommend to clients to do the
following:
- exploit the overlap
- develop a fall-back position
- create a web of rights
- build an IP estate
- build a “wall”
- overprotect (multiple layers of IP
rights protection)
- lay a “minefield”
The most important IP
management and technology licensing strategy is to exploit the overlap between
patents and trade secrets.
8. Initial
Patent/Trade-Secret Evaluation
IP management always
requires deciding during development between seeking patent protection and
maintaining trade secrecy. The Initial Patent/ Trade Secret Evaluation
Questionnaire (Box 1) can be used to facilitate the decision and to help determine
the center of gravity (often patents for products and trade secrets for
processes).20 To avoid the implications of
the term invention and to cover the wide variety of innovations
that may be addressed by this questionnaire, the term development is
used generically.
The 11 questions are
arranged by function, not importance, and roughly correspond to marketing
(questions 1–4), technical (questions 5–8), and legal (questions 9–11) categories.
Each question should be answered on a scale from 1 to 10. The responses are
then totaled. With the current number of questions, the total would range from
11 to 110. If the sum approaches the higher end of the scale (above 75),
trade-secret protection would seem favorable; a sum at the lower end (below 45)
would suggest that patent protection would be more advantageous. At times,
values in the middle range (45–75) will result. Such a score suggests that it
doesn’t really matter which approach is followed initially. For example,
trade-secret protection might be appropriate for manufacturing-process
technology, which competitors might find easier to re-create; patents make
sense for products that can be analyzed or reverse engineered. However, there
need be no prejudice about resorting to the other strategy to protect
collateral aspects and improvements.
To obtain the
most-accurate results from the questionnaire, the following considerations for
each question will be helpful in interpreting the survey responses.
Question 1. If the development is
likely to be commercialized or licensed, patent protection would seem
preferable to trade-secret protection. There might be some exceptions (such as
the Coca-Cola® situation), but presumably these would be
limited to situations where the nature of the product could not be easily
ascertained by reverse engineering (see Question 6).
Note that Question 1
pertains to commercialization of the development itself. Thus the mere use of a
process to produce a commercial product is not commercialization of the process
(see Question 4, about commercial significance). The desirability of patenting
the process itself would depend on the answers to Questions 2–11.
Question 2. Here the aim is to
ascertain whether exclusivity on the development would be meaningful
commercially. A development of marginal commercial importance might be better
kept as a trade secret. One that provided a significant commercial edge,
however, probably should be patented.
Question 3. This addresses the
opposite of the issue in Question 2, namely the defensive value of a patent
publication. Hence, while the development may be of minimum commercial
advantage to the company, thereby favoring trade secrets, a patent (or
publication) should be considered if a competitor’s exclusivity would be
disadvantageous.
Question 4. This is a difficult
question. Some writers have suggested that a product with a short commercial
life favors a patenting approach, while a long life favors trade secrets. In
this author’s view, life span is not a particularly useful criterion since it
depends on factors unrelated to the development itself. Estimating the future
lifespan for a product under development may also be a highly subjective
matter. In some circumstances this question might not have to be considered.
Question 5. The ability to design
around an invention is a function of the nature of the patent protection. If a
claim is easily avoided, its value is considerably reduced. The destructive
effect of trade-secret protection by publication is therefore unchanged, and
the relative value of the trade-secret option is higher (because of the
decreased value of patent protection).
Question 6. Counterbalancing
Question five is the issue of whether, if the trade-secret route is chosen, a
competitor will nevertheless be able to ascertain the nature of the development
from the product. If competitors can reasonably easily ascertain the nature of
the product, patent protection would be favored.
Question 7. The issue of disclosure
is often overlooked. For example, the required disclosure of a culture
collection-deposit number could provide competitors with access to the culture
itself, and this access might greatly outweigh the value of patent protection.
The impact of a disclosure of an unclaimed or intermediate process might also
have a bearing on whether the final product should be patented.
Question 8. In many cases,
evaluating whether others could arrive at the same development independently
could be extremely difficult. If, however, it is known that others are working
in the field, it would seem quite possible that they could arrive at the same
development and patent it first. Consequently, one might eventually be excluded
from using the product if patent protection is not sought.
Question 9. Even though patent
protection might be indicated for other reasons, this could be counterbalanced
by the fact that any coverage eventually obtained would be weak. A weak patent,
ignored by competitors and for which the company is unwilling to sue, is as
good as no patent. In fact, it may be worse, since the opportunity for
trade-secret protection would have been irrevocably lost through publication.
Question 10. Ideally, the
dissemination of information from within the company can be controlled. If not,
however, a trade secret might be lost. If this risk exists, for example when
numerous employees, visitors, and suppliers have access to the development,
patent protection is more attractive. The same question arises with scientific
publications.
Question 11. This question is
related to question nine but goes to the issue of inherent enforceability
rather than patent strength. If detecting infringement would be extremely
difficult, the ultimate value of a patent would be reduced. Such reduced value
must be weighed against the cost of the loss of trade-secret protection caused
by patent publication. If the patent rights cannot be effectively enforced,
then what ensues may become a de facto release of a trade secret.
9. The Patent/Trade
Secret Interface
Trade secrets are the
first line of defense, but they not only come before patents but can go with
patents and even follow patents (see sections 11 and 12, below). Moreover, as a
practical matter, licenses under patents without access to associated or
collateral know-how are often not enough for taking advantage of the patented
technology commercially. This is because patents rarely disclose the ultimate
scaled-up commercial embodiments. Data and know-how, therefore, are immensely
important. In this regard, consider the following persuasive comments:
- In many cases, particularly in
chemical technology, the know-how is the most important part of a
technology transfer agreement.21
- Acquire not just the patents but the
rights to the know-how. Access to experts and records, lab notebooks, and
reports on pilot-scale operations, including data on markets and potential
users of the technology are crucial.22
- It is common practice in industry to
seek and obtain patents on that part of a technology that is amenable to
patent protection, while maintaining related technological data and other
information in confidence. Some regard a patent as little more than an
advertisement for the sale of accompanying know-how.23
- [In technology licensing] related
patent rights generally are mentioned late in the discussion and are
perceived to have ‘insignificant’ value relative to the know-how.24
- Trade secrets are a component of
almost every technology license… [and] can increase the value of a license
up to three to ten times the value of the deal if no trade secrets are
involved.25
A very striking case
about the importance of proprietary know-how comes from Brazil. Brazilian
officials learned a quick and startling lesson when they decided, some years
ago, to translate important patents that issued in developed countries into
Portuguese for the benefit of Brazilian industry. They believed that this was
all that was necessary to enable their industries to practice these foreign
inventions without paying royalties for licenses. Needless to say, without
access to the necessary know-how, this scheme was an utter failure. This
oversight is somewhat surprising, since Brazil, following the amazing progress
and successes of the Asian tigers, had years earlier begun a project of
importing technology (including know-how) from developed countries to be
adapted and improved for local needs. They expected that the cost of importing
the technology would be money well spent. And, in fact, importing the
technologies led not only to exports of improved products, but also to exports
of the resulting improved technology to developing countries in Africa, the
Middle East, and the rest of Latin America. Such an importation/exportation
policy is termed reverse technology transfer.26
To reiterate, patents and
trade secrets are not mutually exclusive but actually highly complementary and
mutually reinforcing. This is partly why the U.S. Supreme Court has recognized
trade secrets as perfectly viable alternatives to patents: “The extension of
trade-secret protection to clearly patentable inventions does not conflict with
the patent policy of disclosure.”27 Interestingly,
in his concurring opinion in the Kewanee Oil28 decision,
Justice Marshall was “persuaded” that “Congress, in
enacting the patent laws, intended merely to offer inventors a limited monopoly
[sic] in exchange for disclosure of their inventions [rather than] to exert
pressure on inventors to enter into this exchange by withdrawing any
alternative possibility of legal protection for their inventions.” Thus, it
is clear that patents and trade secrets can not only coexist but are also in
harmony with each other. “[T]rade-secret/patent coexistence is
well-established, and the two are in harmony because they serve different
economic and ethical functions.”29
In fact, patents and trade
secrets are inextricably intertwined, because the bulk of R&D data and
results, and of associated collateral know-how for any commercially important
innovation, cannot, and need not, be included in a patent application. Such
information deserves, and requires, the protection that trade secrets can
provide. In the past, and sometimes still today, if trade-secret maintenance is
contemplated (for example, for a manufacturing process technology) the question
is always phrased as a choice between patents and trade secrets. For example,
titles of articles discussing the matter read, “Trade Secret vs. Patent
Protection”; “To Patent or Not to Patent?”; “Trade Secret or Patent?”; and “To
Patent or to Padlock?” This perspective imagines that patents and trade secrets
are substantially different in terms of duration and scope of protection and
have clearly perceivable advantages and disadvantages. However, as this chapter
has demonstrated, the perceived differences are illusory. The life of a patent
is roughly 20 years from filing, and an average trade secret may last but a few
years. Nor do they differ in regard to the scope of protection, since virtually
everything produced with human ingenuity is potentially patentable. And while a
patent protects against independent discovery and a trade secret does not, a
patent can lead competitors to attempt to design or invent around it. A
properly guarded and secured trade secret, however, may withstand attempts to
crack it.
10. How Patents and Trade
Secrets are Complementary
It is unnecessary and, in
fact, shortsighted to choose one IP strategy over another. Indeed, the question
is not so much whether to patent or to padlock, but rather what to patent and
what to keep a trade secret. Of course, it may be best to both patent and
padlock, thus integrating patents and trade secrets for the optimal,
synergistic protection of innovation.
It is true that patents
and trade secrets are opposed on the issue of disclosure. Information that is
disclosed in a patent is no longer a trade secret. But patents and trade
secrets are indeed complementary, especially under the following circumstances.
In the critical R&D stage, before any patent applications are filed and
before applications are published and patents issued, trade-secret law dovetails
very nicely with patent law.30 If an
invention has been fully described so as to enable a person skilled in the art
to make and use it, and if the best mode for carrying out the invention, if
available, has been disclosed (as is required in a patent application), all
associated or collateral know-how not divulged can, and should, be retained as
a trade secret. All of the massive R&D data—including data pertaining to
better modes developed after filing, whether or not inventive—should also be
maintained as trade secrets, if the data is not disclosed in subsequent
applications. Complementary patenting and padlocking is tantamount to having
the best of both worlds, especially when technologies are complex and consist
of many patentable inventions and volumes of associated know-how.
11. Best Mode and
Enablement Requirements
The conventional wisdom
is that, because of best mode and enablement requirements, trade secret
protection cannot coexist with patent protection. This, also, is a serious
misconception. These requirements apply only at the time of filing,
only to the knowledge of the inventor(s), and only to the claimed invention.
Patent applications are
filed early in the R&D stage to get the earliest possible filing or
priority date. The patent claims tend to be narrow in order to achieve distance
from prior art. Therefore, the specification normally describes rudimentary lab
experiments or prototypes in only a few pages; the best mode for commercial
manufacture and use are developed later. The best mode and the enablement
requirements are thus no impediments to maintaining, as trade secrets, the
mountains of collateral know-how developed after filing.
The recent decision in CFMT
v. Yieldup International is particularly germane to this point: “Enablement
does not require an inventor to meet lofty standards for success in the
commercial marketplace. Title 35 does not require that a patent disclosure
enable one of ordinary skill in the art to make and use a perfected,
commercially viable embodiment absent a claim limitation to that effect… [T]his
court gauges enablement at the date of the filing, not in light of later
developments.”31 Such reasoning applies
equally well to the best mode requirement.
In Peter Rosenberg’s
opinion, “patents protect only a very small portion of the total technology
involved in the commercial exploitation of an invention… Considerable
expenditure of time, effort, and capital is necessary to transform an
(inventive concept) into a marketable product.”32 In
the process, he adds, valuable know-how is generated, which, even if inventive
and protectable by patents, can be maintained as trade secrets. Rosenberg
asserts that there is “nothing improper in patenting some inventions and
keeping others trade secrets.” Likewise, Tom Arnold asserts that it is “flat
wrong” to assume, as “many courts and even many patent lawyers seem
prone” to do, that “because the patent statute requires a best mode
disclosure, patents necessarily disclose or preempt all the trade secrets that
are useful in the practice of the invention.”33
Gale Peterson also
emphasizes that “the patent statute only requires a written description of
theclaimed invention and how to make and use the claimed invention.”
He therefore advises that, since allowed claims on a patentable system usually
cover much less than the entire scope of the system, the disclosure in the
application be limited to that necessary to support the claims in a 35 U.S.C.
§112 sense (that is, having sufficient information to enable one to make and
use the invention) and that every effort be taken to maintain the remainder of
the system as a trade secret.
In short,
manufacturing-process details, even if available, are not a part of the
statutorily required best mode and enablement disclosure of a patent, and it is
in this process area where “best modes” for scale-up toward actual production
very often lie.
12. Exemplary Trade
Secret Cases
Of course, it goes
without saying that technical and commercial information and collateral know-how
that can be protected with trade secrets cannot include information that is
generally known, readily ascertainable, or constitutes personal skill. But this
exclusion still leaves masses of data and know-how that are protectable as
trade secrets—and often also with additional improvement patents. For example,
GE’s industrial-diamond-process technology is an excellent illustration of the
synergistic integration of patents and trade secrets to secure invulnerable
exclusivity.
The artificial
manufacture of diamonds for industrial uses was very big business for GE, and
they had the best proprietary technology for making these diamonds. GE patented
much of its technology, and when the patents expired, much of the technology
was in the technical literature and in the public domain. But GE also kept
certain distinct inventions and developments secret. The Soviet Union and a Far
East country were very interested in obtaining licenses to this technology, but
GE refused to license to anyone. After getting nowhere with GE, the Far East
interests resorted to industrial espionage. A trusted fast-track star performer
at GE, a national of that country, was enticed with million dollar payments to
spirit away GE’s precious trade secrets. The employee was eventually caught,
tried and jailed.
Similarly, Wyeth has had
an exclusive position on Premarin®, the high-selling hormone-therapy drug,
since 1942. Their patents on the manufacturing process (starting with pregnant
mares’ urine) expired decades ago, but the company also held closely guarded
trade secrets. On behalf of a pharmaceutical company that had been trying to
come out with a generic form of Premarin® for 15 years, Natural
Biologics stole the Wyeth trade secrets. Wyeth sued, prevailed, and got a
sweeping injunction, as this was clearly an egregious case of trade-secret
misappropriation.
These cases illustrate
the value of trade secrets and, more importantly, the merits of marrying
patents with trade secrets. Indeed, these cases show that GE and Wyeth could
have the best of both worlds, patenting their inventions and still keeping
their competitive advantage by maintaining production details in secrecy. Were
GE’s or Wyeth’s policies to rely on trade secrets in this manner or was Coca
Cola’s decision to keep its formula a secret rather than to patent it, unwise
and careless? Clearly not.
Other recent decisions,
such as C&F Packing v. IBP and Pizza Hut and Celeritas
Technologies v. Rockwell International, demonstrate that dual or multiple
IP protection is not only possible but essential to exploit the IP overlap and
provide a fallback.34
In the Pizza Hut case,
for instance, Pizza Hut was made to pay US$10.9 million to C&F for
misappropriation of trade secrets.35 After
many years of research, C&F had developed a process for making and freezing
a precooked sausage for pizza toppings that had the characteristics of freshly
cooked sausage and surpassed other pre-cooked products in price, appearance,
and taste. C&F had obtained a patent on the equipment to make the sausage and
also one on the process for making the sausage. C&F improved the process
after submitting its patent applications and kept its new developments as trade
secrets.
Pizza Hut agreed to buy
C&F’s precooked sausage on the condition that C&F divulge its process
to several other Pizza Hut suppliers, ostensibly to assure that backup
suppliers were available to Pizza Hut. In exchange, Pizza Hut promised to
purchase a large amount of pre-cooked sausage from C&F. Accordingly,
C&F disclosed the process to several Pizza Hut suppliers and entered into
confidentiality agreements with them. Subsequently, Pizza Hut’s other suppliers
learned how to duplicate C&F’s results. Pizza Hut then told C&F that it
would not purchase any more of their sausage without drastic price reductions.
One of Pizza Hut’s
largest suppliers of meat products other than sausage was IBP. Pizza Hut
furnished IBP with a specification and formulation of the sausage toppings and
IBP signed a confidentiality agreement with Pizza Hut concerning this
information. In addition, IBP hired a former supervisor in C&F’s sausage
plant as its production superintendent, but then fired this employee five
months later, after it had implemented its sausage-making process and Pizza Hut
was buying the precooked sausage from IBP.
C&F then brought suit
against IBP and Pizza Hut for patent infringement and misappropriation of trade
secrets, and the court found on summary judgment that the patents of C&F
were invalid because the inventions had been on sale more than one year before
the filing date. However, the court determined that C&F possessed valuable
and enforceable trade secrets, which had indeed been misappropriated. What a
great example of trades secrets serving as backup where patents fail to provide
any protection!
In certain instances, a
patent is a weak instrument indeed, given the many potential patent attrition
factors, such as:
- doubtful patentability due to
patent-defeating grounds
- narrow claims granted by a patent
office
- the fact that “only about 5% of a
large patent portfolio” has commercial value36
- the short life of a patent (average
effective economic life is “only about five years”)37
- enforcement of patents is daunting and
expensive
- limited nature or lack of coverage in
some countries
13. Trade Secrets and
Hybrid Licenses
In trade-secret licensing
practice, the threshold concern one encounters is the so-called black box
dilemma. Two pieces of Anglo-Saxon wisdom describe it vividly. The trade-secret
owner cannot “let the cat out of the bag,” and the potential licensee will not
want to “buy a pig in a poke.” In plainer words, unrestricted disclosure of a
new invention or proprietary know-how would result in the certain loss of
trade-secret rights. On the other side, the potential recipient is unlikely to
acquire something sight unseen. Fortunately, there is a perfect way out of this
quandary. It is a secrecy agreement, also called a nondisclosure agreement, a
confidential disclosure agreement, or a prenegotiation agreement. In
negotiating and drafting such an agreement, the parties have different concerns
that have to be addressed.
Trade secret owners will
want to know:
- What mechanisms and procedures should
be used to divulge the contents of the black box?
- What restrictions should be placed on
recipients with respect to their use of the information in the black box,
if they elect to use the information or if they decide not to use the
information?
- How long and how thoroughly should
recipients be permitted to examine the contents of the black box?
- How much should they charge for a peek
into the black box?
On the other side,
trade-secret recipients will want to know:
- What restrictions should they accept
on use of the information if they want to license and use it?
- What restrictions should they accept
on the future use of the information, if they do not want to license it?
- What if the information is already in
the public domain?
- What if it turns out that they are
already in possession of the information, or an important part of it?
- How much should they pay for a look
into the black box?
A written agreement is
the safest way to preserve secrecy and the best way to arrange an agreement. It
should have provisions that define the area of technology with precision,
establish a confidential legal relationship between the parties, furnish
proprietary information for a specific purpose only, oblige the recipient to hold
information in confidence, and spell out exceptions to secrecy obligations. The
last could include information already in the public domain, information that
later becomes public knowledge other than through the fault of the recipient,
information that is already known to the recipient or that later comes into the
possession of the recipient through a third party that has no secrecy
obligation to the owner. Very importantly, the written agreement should limit
the duration of the secrecy obligation.
Similar critical
provisions should be incorporated into trade-secret licenses, technical
assistance agreements, and hybrid patent/trade-secret licenses. The provisions
should accompany the typical operational clauses that spell out license grants,
royalty payments, indemnities, warranties, terms and termination conditions,
and other miscellaneous matters.
While such hybrid
agreements are very prevalent in the United States, they are quite problematic,
since it is a misuse of a patent or an antitrust violation to exact royalty
payments after a patent ceases to be in force.38 This
could happen, since the lives of trade secrets are potentially indefinite while
patents have a finite lifetime. Hence, depending on how a license agreement is
drafted, in the United States it can become impossible to agree to spread
royalty payments over a specified term that extends beyond the lives of patents
or trade secrets that are embodied in such an agreement. In an American hybrid
licensing agreement, the obligation to pay royalties thus ends, even though valuable
trade secrets are still in play. But there are solutions to this predicament:
- separate patent and trade-secret
agreements
- make initial lump-sum payment(s)
- clearly differentiate between patent
and trade-secret rights
- separate allocation of royalties to
each of the rights
- provide for appropriate decreases in
the royalty rate if patents terminate or are declared invalid or if
applications do not issue
- reduce the royalty-payment period (for
example to 10 years)
- grant a royalty-free license to
patents
- grant a trade-secret license but no
patent license
The choice would depend
largely on the relative role and value of patents and trade secrets in the
given technology.
14. Conclusion
Trade secrets are a
viable mode of IP protection. They can be used instead of patents, but, more
importantly, they can and should be used side-by-side with patents, so that
inventions volumes of collateral know-how can be protected. Far from being
irreconcilable, patents and trade secrets make for a happy marriage as equal
partners: it is patents and trade secrets, not patents or trade
secrets.
With patents and trade
secrets it is clearly possible to cover additional subject matter, strengthen
exclusivity, invoke different remedies in litigation, and have a backup when
the first protection tool becomes invalid or unenforceable. Exploiting the
overlap between patents and trade secrets for optimal protection is a
practical, profitable, and rational IP management and licensing strategy.
License agreements have
become the preferred instruments for technology transfer. Hybrid
patent/trade-secret agreements are also prevalent, since patent disclosures
generally cover only embryonic or early stage R&D results, which are
insufficient for commercializing the patented technology, absent access to
collateral proprietary know-how. This know-how, protectable as trade secrets,
need not be included in patent applications and is usually developed after
filing applications. Such hybrid agreements require clauses that not only
maintain trade secrecy for the benefit of the trade-secret owner, but also
provide appropriate limitations for the protection of the trade-secret
licensee.
Examples of trade secrets
* Business methods
* Business plans
* Business forecasts
* Market analyses
* Marketing plans
* R & D information
* Business relationships
* Product information
* Pricing information
* Financial information
* Profit margin information
* Overhead information
* Cost information
* Purchasing information
* Personnel information
* Office techniques
* Manuals
* Notebooks
* Computer programs
* Computer data bases
* Calculations & processes in computer programs
* Data compilations
* Inventions
* Designs
* Patterns
* Drawings
* Blue prints
* Maps
* Formulas
* Ingredients
* Devices
* Methods
* Machine processes
* Manufacturing techniques
* Manufacturing methods
* Repair techniques
* Repair methods
* Processes
* Systems
* Business plans
* Business forecasts
* Market analyses
* Marketing plans
* R & D information
* Business relationships
* Product information
* Pricing information
* Financial information
* Profit margin information
* Overhead information
* Cost information
* Purchasing information
* Personnel information
* Office techniques
* Manuals
* Notebooks
* Computer programs
* Computer data bases
* Calculations & processes in computer programs
* Data compilations
* Inventions
* Designs
* Patterns
* Drawings
* Blue prints
* Maps
* Formulas
* Ingredients
* Devices
* Methods
* Machine processes
* Manufacturing techniques
* Manufacturing methods
* Repair techniques
* Repair methods
* Processes
* Systems